Submerging market economies
‘THE QUIET COUP’ by Simon Johnson, chief economist
to the IMF in 2007-08, lays bare (as the magazine’s introductory caption
puts it) the alarming and "unpleasant truth" that "the finance industry
has effectively captured [the US] government". (The Atlantic Monthly,
May 2009,
www.theatlantic.com) As an IMF official, Johnson was involved in
many crises in ‘emerging markets’, semi-developed economies like the
South-East Asian countries in 1997, Russia in 1998, and so on. Every
crisis is different, but he sees a common thread:
"Typically, these countries are in a desperate
economic situation for one simple reason – the powerful elites within
them overreached in good times and took too many risks". (This is
somewhat one-sided, given the uneven, contradictory development of the
neo-colonial developing countries.) "Emerging-market governments and
their private-sector allies commonly form a tight-knit… oligarchy,
running the country rather like a profit-seeking company in which they
are the controlling shareholders. When a country like Indonesia or South
Korea or Russia grows, so do the ambitions of its captains of industry.
As masters of their mini-universe, these people make some investments
that clearly benefit the broader economy, but they also start making
bigger and riskier bets. They reckon – correctly, in most cases – that
their political connections will allow them to push onto the government
any substantial problems that arise".
But the oligarchs "get carried away: they waste
money and build massive business empires on a mountain of debt". With
the onset of crisis, there is a downward spiral of corporate
bankruptcies and collapsing banks. "Yesterday’s ‘public-private
partnerships’ are relabelled ‘crony capitalism’." Governments find
various ways of bailing out their big business friends. "Meanwhile,
needing to squeeze someone, most emerging-market governments look
first to ordinary working folk – at least until the riots grow too
large".
Johnson finds a strong resemblance to the US crisis:
"In its depth and suddenness, the US economic and financial crisis is
shockingly reminiscent of moments we have recently seen in emerging
markets (and only in emerging markets): South Korea (1997), Malaysia
(1998), Russia and Argentina (time and again). In each of those cases,
global investors, afraid that the country or its financial sector
wouldn’t be able to pay off mountainous debt, suddenly stopped lending.
And in each case, that fear became self-fulfilling, as banks that
couldn’t roll over their debt did, in fact, become unable to pay. This
is precisely what drove Lehman Brothers into bankruptcy on September 15,
causing all sources of funding to the US financial sector to dry up
overnight. Just as in emerging-market crises, the weakness in the
banking system has quickly rippled out into the rest of the economy,
causing a severe economic contraction and hardship for millions of
people".
Without using the precise, appropriate term, Johnson
points to the role of US finance capital, which has become the dominant
faction of the US capitalist class. "But there’s a deeper and more
disturbing similarity [with development in neo-colonial countries]:
elite business interests – financiers, in the case of the US – played a
central role in creating the crisis, making ever-larger gambles, with
the implicit backing of the government, until the inevitable collapse.
More alarming, they are now using their influence to prevent precisely
the sorts of reforms that are needed, and fast, to pull the economy out
of its nosedive. The government seems helpless, or unwilling, to act
against them".
Mesmerised by Wall Street
BLAME HAS BEEN targeted at an array of people and
policies. Greedy bankers and irresponsible government officials (who
lowered interest rates and loosened the money supply). Financiers
proposed financial instruments they did not understand. Regulators
turned a blind eye to shady practices. The twin deficits – the Federal
government and the US trade deficit – allowed consumer spending and the
housing bubble to grow on the basis of ever mounting debt. China
supplied cheap goods and provided market-supporting credit. All these
developments benefited the finance sector, and all attempts to limit
potentially risky activities were brushed aside.
From the early 1980s, the finance sector boomed,
becoming increasingly powerful. The monetary policy of Paul Volcker,
chair of the Federal Reserve, which supported high interest rates and
reduced inflation, favoured money lenders and those trading financial
assets. Republican president, Ronald Reagan, opened up a period of
deregulation, which was continued under Bill Clinton (Democrat) and
George W Bush (Republican). There was an unprecedented boom of money
trading outside the previous framework of the commercial banks through
securitisation, with the proliferation of a host of exotic derivatives.
The growth of pension funds and individual saving
plans also expanded the profit-making opportunities of investment banks,
hedge funds, and so on. The accelerated globalisation of financial
markets enormously extended the scope of speculative activity,
channelling fabulous profits into the coffers of money traders
(including the special trading units of commercial banks).
"Not surprisingly, Wall Street ran with these
opportunities. From 1973 to 1985, the financial sector never earned more
than 16% of domestic corporate profits. In 1986, that figure reached
19%. In the 1990s, it oscillated between 21% and 30%, higher than it had
ever been in the post-war period. This decade, it reached 41%. Pay rose
just as dramatically. From 1948 to 1982, average compensation pay in the
financial sector ranged between 99% and 108% of the average for all
domestic private industries. From 1983, it shot upward, reaching 181% in
2007".
Finance capitalists concentrated massive wealth into
their hands in recent years and, as a result, have exerted enormous
political power. Johnson points to the ‘cultural capital’ acquired by
the finance sector, ‘a belief system’: "Once, perhaps, what was good for
General Motors was good for the country. Over the past decade, the
attitude took hold that what was good for Wall Street was good for the
country". In other words, ultra-free market ideology was a powerful
force in shaping conditions favourable to finance capital: "Faith in
free financial markets grew into conventional wisdom – trumpeted on the
editorial pages of The Wall Street Journal and on the floor of
Congress".
Wall Street firms were among the top contributors to
political campaigns, Republican and Democrat. Leaders rotated between
Wall Street and Washington, people like James Rubin (Clinton’s Treasury
Secretary), Alan Greenspan (from Wall Street to the Fed and back again),
and now Tim Geithner, Barack Obama’s Treasury Secretary. Politicians,
journalists and academics (says Johnson) were "mesmerized by Wall
Street, always and utterly convinced that whatever the banks said was
true".
Systemic flaw
BUT IT HAS all come to an end. The beginning of the
unwinding of the subprime housing bubble in 2007 triggered a world-wide
seizure of the banking system. The ensuing credit squeeze produced an
economic downturn. This in turn has aggravated the financial crisis. The
illusion of limitless, risk-free profits has been totally shattered. The
recovery, when it comes, is likely to be long-drawn-out and painful,
particularly for workers who, as always, will bear the main burden of
the crisis.
According to Brooks, Johnson’s analysis is just
another ‘greed narrative’. Investment bankers, pursuing bigger and
bigger profits, became increasingly powerful, "the US economy got
finance heavy and finance mad, and finally collapsed". This just shows
how shallow this columnist is. Johnson’s The Quiet Coup accurately
describes a structural change in US capitalism – which also developed in
Britain and other economies following the ‘Anglo-Saxon model’ – with the
emergence of finance capital as the dominant section of the capitalist
class.
Yet Johnson’s analysis also has its limitations.
Nowhere does he explain the underlying reasons for the rise of the
financial oligarchy. This means that, ultimately, he fails to analyse
the causes of the current financial-economic crisis, which he simply
blames on the rise of the oligarchy. Like any other structural change in
capitalism, it is ultimately rooted in the underlying relations of
production, in the inner processes of the capitalist economy.
The swing to financial investment and speculation
over the last three-and-a-half decades arises from a crisis of
over-accumulation of capital. During the post-war upswing (1950-73),
capitalism enjoyed very favourable conditions, especially in the
advanced capitalist countries. Historically high levels of investment
and productivity growth supported both relatively high wage levels
(sustaining consumer demand) and a rise in profitability (encouraging
new investment). The growth of state expenditure also supported
investment and demand for goods and services. This period is now
referred to as the ‘golden age’ of capitalism.
The favourable relationships of that period,
however, were undermined by the inner contradictions of capitalism. In
particular, new investment in the means of production (plant, machinery,
etc) no longer produced the level of profits required by the
capitalists. "Between 1968 and 1973 the profit rate for the ACCs
[advanced capitalist countries] as a whole fell in the business and
manufacturing sectors by one fifth". (Andrew Glyn: Capitalism since 1945
[1991], p182) In the US, for instance, the profit rate for manufacturing
fell from the previous peak of 36.4% to 22% in 1973. Significantly, the
end of the upswing, marked by the 1973 oil price shock, was marked by an
explosion of speculation, especially in commodities and commercial
property. In their search for higher profits, the capitalists turned
more and more towards financial investment, which became increasingly
speculative. The Thatcher-Reagan ‘revolution’ – deregulation,
privatisation, tax changes for the super-rich, and an offensive on
workers’ rights – was carried through under pressure of the underlying
economic change and, of course, enormously widened the scope for
speculative capital.
The growth of investible funds (from corporate
profits, pension funds, investment banks, etc) continuously grew, but
far outstripped the opportunities for profitable investment in new
productive capacity. In capitalist terms, there was an ‘over-supply’ of
capital. Not that millions of people did not need essential goods and
services, but there was insufficient money-backed demand because of the
limited income of the working class. Overcapacity developed in most
major industries, so why should capitalists invest in new means of
production?
For the major capitalist economies, the growth rate
of fixed capital stock (a measure of capital accumulation) in the 1990s
and 2000s has been only half that of the 1960s. In the US, the growth
fell from 4% per annum in the 1920s to 3% in the 1990s and 2% in the
2000s: "capital stock growth started from an exceptionally low point in
the early 1990s. The most positive conclusion from [the data] would be
that the investment boom of the later 1990s halted the seemingly
inexorable downward trend in the growth rate of the capital stock which
had begun in the late 1960s. Moreover, when the boom came to an end in
2000, capital stock growth plummeted more steeply than ever before".
(Andrew Glyn: Capitalism Unleashed [2006], pp86, 134)
Surprisingly, perhaps, this analysis was confirmed
in 2007 by a Morgan Stanley economist, whose role is to advise investors
in the financial sector. Rejecting the ‘conventional wisdom’ that the
flood of cheap credit was merely the result of "the central banks’
irresponsibly easy monetary policy", Stephen Jen wrote: "I believe that
the more important source of global liquidity is the (curiously) low
capex/capital stock in the world". (Capex is short for capital
expenditure.) In spite of low interest rates and an abundance of credit,
"there has been a curious reluctance on the part of the corporate sector
in the world to invest in physical assets, ie capex has been
surprisingly low…" Jen’s explanation emphasises the "intense uncertainty
regarding the outlook of the global economy [which] may have forced
companies to restrain their capex plans… multinational corporations may
have attached a certain risk to expanding capacity in emerging markets,
due to uncertainties regarding both political and economic policies".
(Low Investment is the Main Source of Global Liquidity, Morgan Stanley
Global Economic Forum, 23 February 2007)
Credit plays an essential part in the process of
capitalist production, as Karl Marx showed. But, in the last 30 years,
finance capital became increasingly parasitic. As Johnson’s figures
show, finance swallowed an ever increasing share of total profits. The
pressure of the finance sector for short-term profit also raised the
profitability of many manufacturing and service industries, mostly
through downsizing and intensifying the exploitation of workers. But the
biggest profits for finance came from churning the huge volumes of cash
flowing around the global economy.
Some originated, as we have seen, in the ‘surplus’
profits of big corporations which had no incentive to reinvest in new
productive capacity. But the biggest profits have come from trading
financial assets using ultra-cheap credit borrowed from economies with
big surpluses, like Japan, China and the oil-producers. Much of the
super-profits have come, not from the production of new wealth, but from
the redistribution of savings and profits from small and medium savers,
and investors to the super-rich, elite financiers who run the big hedge
funds, investment banks and private equity firms.
An ongoing crisis
THESE, IN JOHNSON’S language, constitute the
financial oligarchy. Its leaders were seen, until the collapse, as
‘masters of the universe’. But, in reality, they are the alchemists of
capitalist impasse, conjuring up capital gains from speculative trading.
The domination of finance capital arises from the inability of
capitalism in this period to develop the productive forces in a
broad-based way. There has been a surge of investment in some sectors,
where there is new technology, and in some countries like China (where
growth is still very uneven). But, on a world scale, the accumulation of
capital, which should be the dynamic motor of capitalist growth, has
collided with the barrier of private ownership, which demands profitable
returns as the condition of new investment.
Johnson argues that all toxic assets should be
written off at their true market value (a lot lower than their current
valuation). Banks with insufficient capital should be nationalised,
broken up, and eventually sold back to private owners. But he clearly
does not believe that this is what will happen. The US government has
effectively partially nationalised several big banks and financial
institutions, but it has not taken control. Like the Bush
administration, the Obama government is attempting to muddle through
with a series of bank-by-bank deals, handing out state subsidies that
are too complex for the public to understand. "Throughout the crisis",
writes Johnson, "the government has taken extreme care not to upset the
interests of the financial institutions, or to question the basic
outlines of the system that got us here".
There are now two scenarios, says Johnson. With
government bailouts, the US and other major capitalist economies may
muddle through. Alternatively, there could be a deepening world
financial and economic crisis. It would be wrong (he says) to rely on
the consoling idea that ‘it can’t be as bad as the great depression’ of
the 1930s: "What we face now could, in fact, be worse than the Great
Depression – because the world is now so much more interconnected and
because the banking sector is now so big. We face a synchronised
downturn in almost all countries, a weakening of confidence among
individuals and firms, and major problems for government finances".
Whatever scenario plays out, the capitalist ruling class will do all it
can to offload the effects of this deep economic crisis onto the backs
of the world’s working class and poor.